Financial incentives reduce the incremental costs of the most energy-efficient appliances and are typically used with a view to accelerating their market penetration. They can thus make an important contribution to increasing the share of best available technologies (BAT) in the market and to replace existing old low-efficiency appliances. However, they are mainly appropriate for appliances with a high spread of energy efficiency levels between the least and most energy-efficient models on offer and with high absolute energy savings. Good candidates are usually refrigerators and freezers, heat pump clothes driers, commercial food preparation, refrigeration, and washing appliances, and maybe TV sets. There are different options for providing financial incentives, and the choice will depend on national circumstances.
Financial incentives are mainly implemented in the form of grants or tax reductions. It is important to monitor the incentive schemes and end them when the very energy-efficient appliances have achieved approximately 50% market share, as they would then loose effectiveness and free-rider effects may become too high. Financial incentives are not the appropriate policy instrument for all appliances. They are most effective for appliances with a high energy efficiency range among the different models and a high annual energy saving potential per unit. Otherwise, the incentive justified by the savings that can be made would become too small to impress and attract consumers to buy the more energy-efficient appliances.
Financial incentives are applied for two basic purposes: 1) to incentivise the purchase of a very energy-efficient new product instead of one with lower energy efficiency (market transformation) and 2) to incentivise replacement of old very inefficient products by a new very energy-efficient product (replacement scheme/scrappage premium). However, the latter should be restricted to product groups, within which old appliances have a very high energy consumption and savings are high enough to refinance the full cost of the new, energy-efficient appliance within their lifetime.
This policy instrument is especially effective for cases when investors or investor-users are unaware that energy-efficient appliances exist or that the total of their purchase price and energy cost is lower than for less efficient models, or when they perceive energy savings as being too low in comparison to up-front investment costs. For these customers, the incentive can be the final convincing argument to invest in highly energy-efficient technology. Those customers who are not aware of energy efficiency potentials may be sensitised by a financial incentive scheme.
Finally, other than regulatory measures such as minimum energy performance standards (MEPS) that usually only remove the least efficient appliances from the market, financial incentive schemes can be a significant pull-factor for the market towards very energy-efficient appliances, as shown in the graph: only the most efficient models will be rewarded.
Advantages
|
Disadvantages
|
The aim of the policy is to foster the purchase of energy-efficient appliances. It can also be used to facilitate market penetration of innovative technologies or to accelerate the exchange of very inefficient old appliances.
Worldwide implementation status
Financial incentive schemes for energy efficient appliances are implemented in many countries worldwide.
Governance level
Usually, financial incentives are offered by national governments. Depending on the specific measure and legislative framework, it can be at the international, national, regional and local level and also be offered by energy companies as part of their measures to fulfil an energy efficiency obligation. It is essential to avoid competing schemes.
This policy is focused on appliances. It is especially appropriate for common appliances with a high spread of energy efficiency levels between the least and most energy-efficient models on offer and with high absolute energy savings, such as refrigerators and freezers, cooking stoves, clothes dryers, or televisions, and commercial food cooling and laundry equipment.
Appliances covered:
Consumer organisations, energy agencies, and energy companies are sometimes involved in the implementation of the policy and thus benefit from increasing service demand.
The following pre-conditions are necessary to implement financial incentives:
Agencies or other actors responsible for implementation
As financial incentive schemes often involve the review and administration of funding applications by customers and finally the payment, they are usually not handled by ministries but rather implemented by Energy Agencies, energy companies, or retailers directly. Consumer and producer associations may be partners to implement the policy.
Funding
Funding can be provided via the energy prices and tariffs, since it will also be the energy consumers benefiting from the energy savings. This will be the usual source in case of energy companies implementing the programme to fulfil an Energy Saving Obligation. Creating a special levy on energy prices to provide the funding is another possibility.
Cross-financing from government budgets (taxes) is possible too, e.g. for efficiency funds. Market-based financing includes, in addition to Energy Saving Obligation schemes, Emission Certificates auctioning funds or, an alternative source for developing countries and emerging economies, climate finance, such as Programmes of Activities (PoA) under the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) or Nationally Appropriate Mitigation Actions (NAMAs).
Test procedures
An agreed test procedure for measuring the standard energy consumption of an appliance is the precondition for deciding whether the appliance is energy-efficient enough to qualify for the financial incentive. If there is an energy label for the type of appliance, there will be a test procedure underlying this label, and so normally this test procedure or the label will be used directly.
In addition, in order to prove that the programmes are effective in saving energy and reaching defined efficiency standards, agreed, reliable, and standardised methods for calculating savings, economic benefits, and costs need to be developed and used.
For this policy, not all stakeholders need to be consulted, but for the institutional design, consultation of the target group (including appliance retail trade and manufacturers/importers) may be sensible to secure optimal functioning and public awareness of the programme. The first step is an encompassing market study. If other policies (regulation/labelling) have already been carried out, respective studies may be used and synergies realised.
The second step involves the identification of possible target BAT appliances, and the respective energy performance levels, which may be incentivised and involves also the consideration of different incentive amounts and types (grant, tax deduction etc.). At this stage, scenario modelling of the effects for setting different policies are recommended.
In a final step, the incentive scheme needs to be set up preferably at an existing institution experienced in consumer consultation and public relations. It is important to design a scheme that is as easily accessible as possible, e.g., cooperating with retailers for payment of the incentive.
A thorough monitoring and evaluation system should be set up in order to identify real effects.
Quantified target
The policy can quantify targets (number of units, number of participants, targeted energy savings).
International co-operations
Countries can co-operate by exchanging information and experience on principles as well as practical details, problems, and solutions of problems encountered when implementing such incentive programmes. Example can be how to make participation as easy as possible, or how to minimise free-rider effects.
Providing climate finance to developing and emerging countries for funding financial incentive programmes is another potential way of co-operation.
Monitoring
The implementing institutions need to set up a monitoring system covering data on individual cases: the appliances receiving a financial incentive and their energy performance or energy label classes, the amount of energy saved (kWh/yr per appliance), the total cost of the appliances, the amount of grants or tax credits and the programme administration and communication costs. In order to verify office book-keeping, sample checks in the field are useful.
Evaluation
It is important to evaluate this policy in order to find out if the incentive provided is adequate. In order to find out whether the funding is used effectively, the number of new appliances that are bought and how much more efficient they are compared to the inefficient appliances that would have been purchased without the programme, or to the old appliances that were replaced, could be assessed. The market share of the addressed energy-efficient appliances has to be monitored, so the incentive can be concluded when a certain market share (appr. 50%) is reached.
In addition to the data directly monitored for the energy efficiency programmes, evaluation of net energy savings compared to baseline trends should address side-effects such as rebound, multiplier, and free-rider effects, and the ‘lifetime’ and potential deterioration of energy savings.
For the economic benefits from the perspective of the national economy/society, standard values for the incremental energy supply costs that will be avoided in the long run for a kWh of energy or a kW of load should be developed by the regulatory authority.
The evaluation should be done by independent institutes or consultants.
Design for sustainability aspects
The policy can be complemented e.g. if a recycling programme is added to save resources and avoid harmful emissions to the environment. People who make use of the financial incentives then have to prove that the replaced appliance has been recycled.
Other sustainability aspects can be included in the definition of measures incentivised (health/environmental aspects).
Co-benefits
The co-benefit of this policy is that the demand for energy-efficient appliances that usually have a higher added value rises, which creates growth in retail and production of such appliances. Several energy efficiency market segments can be stimulated with labour market effects in these sectors.
The following barriers are possible during the implementation of the policy
The implementation of the policy can be hampered if not enough funding is provided and if the control system is not thorough enough to impede fraud.
Another typical barrier is low response and participation from the target groups. This may be due either to low awareness of the programme, uncertainty of the benefits of energy efficiency, financial incentives being too low, application procedures too cumbersome, or supply-side market actors not sufficiently skilled or unmotivated to market energy efficiency and the programme.
The following measures can be undertaken to overcome the barriers
The policy should be monitored and the use of financial incentives should be controlled at least through sample checks.
Funding for financial incentive programmes can be stabilised by delegating implementation to energy companies, e.g. as part of an energy saving obligation. Another option is a dedicated energy efficiency levy and funds, or using revenues from auctioning emission rights. For developing and emerging countries, climate finance is another potential way of funding financial incentive programmes.
Measures to increase participation will depend on the reasons identified for low programme uptake (see above for potential reasons). They can include better communication of the incentive programme and the benefits of energy-efficient appliances, easing application and participation, increasing the incentives for consumers and / or for retailers and sales staff, or offering training for sales persons.
Financial incentive programmes can be very powerful tools used to promote very energy-efficient appliances. The following bigEE model examples of good practice demonstrate the achievable energy savings:
Brazil’s Electric Utilities’ Refrigerator Programme
Between 2008 and 2010 45 utilities carried out refrigerator replacement programmes. In total,383,760 appliances were replaced from 2008 to 2010 which saved 186,294 MWh/year and reduced peak demand by 23,277 kW.
Energy saved in total electricity consumption for low-income households: Average total monthly consumption among a sample of customers of one utility fell from 167 kWh to 94 kWh after the replacement programme (a reduction of 44%) (Jannuzzi 2007).
The Dutch energy rebate scheme “EnergiePremieRegeling”
In November 2001, almost two years after the start of the EPR, one third of Dutch households had applied for the EPR rebates. Of this, around two thirds concerned domestic appliances. The introduction of the EPR has led to an enormous growth of the supply of A-labelled appliances.
The market share of A-labelled washing machines grew from 40 to 88% over the 1999-2001 period. For refrigerators this was from 26 to 67%. The proportion of A labelled appliances doubled. According to estimates by Wuppertal Institute, energy savings for household appliances of 300 GWh/year plus 500 GWh/year in heating energy for buildings and 0.3 million tons of CO2 were realized with the programme (including the market transformation effect and other side effects).
The tax rebate scheme from Italy
BIO IS et al. (2008) estimate energy savings of 43.6GWh (9.6 ktoe) in the first 9 months and CO2 reductions of 27.7 kt CO2. In the first 9 months, 67% of the total sales were A+ or A++ appliances (Bio IS et al. 2008, p.99). The share of A+ and A++ labelled appliances increased by 28% compared to 2006.
The expected costs depend on the design of the programme, the duration and the rebate or incentive for each appliance. Some examples from three different incentive programmes are listed below (read more on these programmes in the bigEE good practice files):
Brazil’s Electric Utilities’ Refrigerator Programme
The new refrigerator is supposed to save at least the same amount of electricity as the difference between the subsidised tariff and the residential one → 53% (Jannuzzi 2007).
The Dutch energy rebate scheme “EnergiePremieRegeling”
In total, about 15% of the ecotax was used for the energy rebate scheme. The amount of funds available to the citizens for 2000 and 2001 was €158 million of which 97% was actually spent. The additional implementation costs (including information and awareness campaigns) by the utility companies were 20% of this expenditure (ca. €41 million). 42% was used to increase the demand for energy-efficient domestic appliances.
Joosen et al. (2004) estimated a cost of conserved energy of between 4 and 8 Eurocent/kWh for the programme costs (rebates plus administration). Due to the rebates, the actions were on average cost-effective for the consumers who took action.
Italian government’s tax rebate scheme
The costs for the government in the first nine months of 2007 were estimated to be between €90 million and €130 million (BIO IS et al. 2008, p.98).
Well-designed financial incentive schemes for energy-efficient appliances can be cost-effective for consumers and society. However, care must be taken to achieve high participation and energy savings, and low free-rider effects, as many evaluations show. Here are some examples from bigEE’s files.
Brazil’s Electric Utilities’ Refrigerator Programme
Only 26 of the 94 programmes have an expected cost-benefit ratio under 1.0; i.e., these are cost-effective. The rest are not cost-effective, but potentially have social and environment benefits. It has to be noted that these programmes cover the full cost of the new energy-efficient appliances, not just a rebate of 10 to 20 % on the purchase price as in most financial incentive programmes.
The Dutch energy rebate scheme “EnergiePremieRegeling”
Joosen et al. (2004) estimated a cost of conserved energy of between 4 and 8 Eurocent/kWh for the programme costs (rebates plus administration). This is about equal to long-run marginal costs of energy supply, so the programme was about cost-effective. Due to the rebates, the actions were on average cost-effective for the consumers who took action.
In addition, another benefit of the programme was that prices of A-labelled appliances decreased (up to 25%).
York, Dan; Molina, Maggie; Neubauer, Max; Nowak, Seth; Nadel, Steven; Chittum, Anna; Elliott, Neal; Farley, Kate; Foster, Ben; Sachs, Harvey; Witte, Patti (2013): Frontiers of Energy Efficiency: Next Generation Programs Reach for High Energy Savings. January 2013. ACEEE Report Number U131. www.bigee.net/s/1s8cjv
|
Italian Income Tax Credit Scheme
Type: Financial incentives |
Italy |
|
Rebate scheme for energy-efficient appliances and other actions
Type: Financial incentives |
Netherlands |
|
Utilities’ Refrigerator replacement programme
Type: Financial incentives |
Brazil |
|
Chinese National Improved Stove Programme
Type: Financial incentives |
China |
|
Energy Revolution
Type: Financial incentives |
Cuba |
makes energy efficiency in buildings and appliances transparent. For investors, policy-makers and actors involved in implementation and consultancy. Learn more ...
© 2024 | Built by the Wuppertal Institute for Climate, Environment and Energy | All rights reserved. | Imprint | Privacy Policy